欧美精品在欧美一区二区少妇,久久久久成人影视,99热在线精品呀,草莓视频手机在线观看

當前位置:

2011年3月高級口譯閱讀上半場第三篇原文(新東方版)

發(fā)表時間:2011/4/28 13:43:17 來源:互聯(lián)網 點擊關注微信:關注中大網校微信
關注公眾號

為了幫助廣大考生系統(tǒng)的復習翻譯資格考試,更好的掌握翻譯資格考試的重點內容,小編特編輯匯總了2011年翻譯資格考試的重點輔導資料,希望對您此次參加考試有所幫助!

You know Adam Smith for his "invisible hand," the mysterious force that steers the selfish economic decisions of individuals toward a result that leaves us all better off. It's been a hugely influential idea, one that during the last few decades of the 20th century began to take on the trappings of a universal truth.

Lately, though, the invisible hand has been getting slapped. The selfish economic decisions of home buyers, mortgage brokers, investment bankers and institutional investors over the past decade clearly did not leave us all better off. Did Smith have it wrong?

No, Smith did not have it wrong. It's just that some of his self-proclaimed disciples have given us a terribly incomplete picture of what he believed. The man himself used the phrase invisible hand only three times: once in the famous passage from The Wealth of Nations that everybody cites; once in his other big book, The Theory of Moral Sentiments; and once in a posthumously published history of astronomy (in which he was talking about "the invisible hand of Jupiter" — the god, not the planet). For Smith, the invisible hand was but one of an array of interesting social and economic forces worth thinking about. (See the 100 best books of all time.)

Why did the invisible hand emerge as the one idea from Smith's work that everybody remembers? Mainly because it's so simple and powerful. If the invisible hand of the market really can be relied on at all times and in all places to deliver the most prosperous and just society possible, then we'd be idiots not to get out of the way and let it work its magic. Plus, the supply-meets-demand straightforwardness of the invisible-hand metaphor lends itself to mathematical treatment, and math is the language in which economists communicate with one another.

Hardly anything else in Smith's work is nearly that simple or consistent. Consider The Theory of Moral Sentiments, his long-neglected other masterpiece, published 17 years before The Wealth of Nations, in 1759. I recently cracked open a new 250th-anniversary edition, complete with a lucid introduction by economist Amartya Sen, in hopes that it would make clearer how we ought to organize our economy. (See a special report on important economists.)

Fat chance. Most of the book is an account of how we decide whether behavior is good or not. In Smith's telling, the most important factor is our sympathy for one another. "To restrain our selfish, and to indulge our benevolent affections, constitutes the perfection of human nature," he writes. But he goes on to say that "the commands and laws of the Deity" (he seems to be referring to the Ten Commandments) are crucial guides to conduct too. Then, in what seems to be a strange detour from those earthly and divine parameters, he argues that the invisible hand ensures that the selfish and sometimes profligate spending habits of the rich tend to promote the public good.

There are similar whiplash moments in The Wealth of Nations. The dominant theme running through the book is that self-interest and free, competitive markets can be powerful forces for prosperity and for good. But Smith also calls for regulation of interest rates and laws to protect workers from their employers. He argues that the corporation, the dominant form of economic organization in today's world, is an abomination.

The point here isn't that Smith was right in every last one of his prescriptions and proscriptions. He was an 18th century Scottish scholar, not an all-knowing being. Many of his apparent self-contradictions are just that — contradictions that don't make a lot of sense. (See the best business deals of 2009.)

But Smith was also onto something that many free-market fans who pledge allegiance to him miss. The world is a complicated place. Markets don't exist free of societies and governments and regulators and customs and moral sentiments; they are entwined. Also, while markets often deliver wondrous results, an outcome is not by definition good simply because the market delivers it. Some other standards have to be engaged.

Applying Smith's teachings to the modern world, then, is a much more complex and doubtful endeavor than it's usually made out to be. He certainly wouldn't have been opposed to every government intervention in the market. On financial reform, it's easy to imagine Smith supporting the creation of a Consumer Financial Protection Agency and crackdowns on giant financial institutions. He might have also favored the just-passed health care reform bill, at least the part that requires states to set up exchanges to ensure retail competition for health insurance.

Then again, he might not have. Asking "What would Adam Smith say?" is a lot easier than conclusively answering it. It is pretty clear, though, that he wouldn't just shout, "Don't interfere with the invisible hand!" and leave it at that.

相關內容:

2011年春季上海高級口譯真題翻譯原文匯總

編輯推薦:

2011年全國翻譯專業(yè)資格(水平)考試免費短信提醒

2011年全國翻譯專業(yè)資格(水平)考試網絡課堂免費試聽

2011年全國翻譯專業(yè)資格(水平)考試免費在線模考

2011年全國翻譯資格網絡輔導全程強化班 現在報名八折優(yōu)惠

(責任編輯:vstara)

2頁,當前第1頁  第一頁  前一頁  下一頁
最近更新 考試動態(tài) 更多>
亚洲网久久久| 超碰97人人做人人爱少妇 | 上高县| 伊人激情在线视频| 日本国精在线一区| 日工地少妇毛片| av电影在线| 色婷婷五月综合图片| 91狠狠操她| 99re在线视频| 亚洲香蕉在线| 老湿机午夜免费| 精品人妻无码区二区三区 | 亚州AⅤ天堂| 久久乐国产精品亚洲综合| 人妻在线综合| 另类图片日韩| 天天影视福利| 草草爱| 久久涩久久| swag大奶子99| 日韩精品无码综合一区| 亚洲综合在线另类色区奇米| 欧美淫秽网免费观看| 亚洲制服无码黑丝后入| 夜夜99| 国产视频极品区| 无码综合| 一级黄片无码| 91国自产拍最新| 亚洲网天天| 色8激情欧美成人久久综合电影| 欧美区在线| 91超喷在线| 在线观看中文无码| 四虎影院888| 无码人妻不卡视频| 日韩欧美视频一区| 亚洲乱码在线卡一卡二卡新区| 亚洲性爱视频一区二区| 社长ol丝袜人妻秘书|